Agenda Advancing economics in business The shift towards defined-contribution pensions: are the risks overstated? There is a clear shift towards pensions in defined-contribution form, although the nature, extent and pace of the shift differ between Member States. This article examines the risks and advantages of DC pension schemes, focusing on one key aspect of pension scheme design— namely the framework for DC pension investment
The pension landscape in Europe has been, and
and structure of DC occupational pensions schemes
continues to be, undergoing significant changes. These
emerging in the EU, the report examines not only the
changes have led to a shift towards individuals having to
investment framework but three other aspects of scheme
take more responsibility for the provision of adequate
design which are not examined in this article: the
income for their retirement. This shift manifests itself in
measures introduced to facilitate individual choice and
decision-making; scheme governance; and the scope forcost efficiencies in pension provision. The shift to defined-contribution pensions There is greater reliance on private sector pensions Advantages of DC schemes to substitute or supplement state pension benefits.
The shift towards DC has been subject to extensive
Pension schemes increasingly take the form of
commentary and much criticism—often unfounded,
defined-contribution (DC) schemes, in which
since, as discussed below, the risks associated with DC
individuals’ retirement wealth depends on the
schemes are often overstated while their advantages are
contributions made and the performance of the
often downplayed. As such, there is sometimes a
investments in capital markets, as opposed to
mismatch between perception on the one hand, and
defined-benefit (DB) schemes, in which the scheme
economic reality and the fundamental characteristics of
sponsor guarantees a certain income level (usually
different pension scheme structures on the other. in the form of an income replacement rate) at retirement. Pension provision is not a free lunch All pension arrangements are premised on the payment
The shift towards pensions in DC form is occurring
of income at a future date. In a funded system, assets
across Europe, although the extent, nature and pace of
accumulate to meet the cost of future pension payments,
the shift vary between countries. Existing DB pension
and for a pension scheme to be self-financing, the
schemes offered by employers are being restructured
contributions made to the scheme in the accumulation
and/or new schemes introduced that are mainly of
phase, plus the return on the investments, must generate
DC-type, including in those countries where private
an accumulated asset value that matches the value of
pension provision has historically not been significant.
pension payments. This applies to all types of funded
Given that the shift towards DC is an economic reality
pension scheme, regardless of whether the scheme is
and DB pensions are not, and may not become,
defined as DB or DC. However, contribution rates to DB
accessible for many individuals, the relevant policy
and DC schemes tend to differ in practice. For example,
question is how DC schemes can be designed to deliver
where the shift from DB to DC is explained by the need
effective retirement provision for individuals.
of employers to reduce their pension costs, it is oftenaccompanied by a reduction in the overall value of the
This article considers DC pension schemes, and focuses
pension contributions and, therefore, a reduction in
on one key aspect of pension scheme design—namely
pension benefits. Lower contributions imply lower levels
the framework for DC pension investment. It draws on
of retirement wealth but for reasons that have little to do
Oxera’s recent study for the European Fund and Asset
with the shift to DC pensions per se, as discussed below.
Management Association. Using evidence on the growth
This article is based on the Oxera report ‘Defined-contribution Pension Schemes: Risks and Advantages for Occupational Retirement Provision’,prepared for the European Fund and Asset Management Association, January 2008. Available at www.oxera.com.
Oxera Agenda
The shift towards DC pensions: are the risks overstated?
All types of pension carry risk Figure 1 Illustration of spectrum of risks and scheme structures
The fundamental difference between DBand DC pensions relates instead to the
allocation of risk between the parties. Themain source of risk to an individual in a DC
given level of contributions, assetaccumulation in the individual account
Wage path and job tenure risk shifts to member
depends on financial market returns andthe chosen investment approach. In a DB
scheme, this risk is borne by thesponsoring employers who will have to change their level
schemes can be regarded as two ends of a broad
of contributions as the investment returns vary in order to
spectrum along which lie a variety of arrangements that
differ in their allocation of risks (see Figure 1).
While pure DC schemes expose individuals to
– DC schemes can be structured to achieve specific
investment risk, they are not necessarily riskier for
target outcomes or reallocate the investment risk
individuals than DB schemes. The latter expose
away from the scheme member—eg, by implementing
individuals to other types of risk, and this riskiness is
a minimum-return guarantee by the sponsoring
– DB schemes tied to the final years of earnings expose
– In DB schemes, the scheme sponsor can assume the
individuals to risk associated with changing wages
wage path or job tenure risk that would otherwise be
and jobs during their career. As confirmed in a
borne by the individual by adopting average-salary
growing body of academic literature, DC schemes,
schemes rather than a benefit formula that depends
where contributions depend on life-time earnings and
pension rights tend to be more portable, can deliverbetter value (in terms of what individuals will get for
– Through implementing hybrid arrangements, the plan
their direct and indirect contributions) if the wage path
sponsor can shift some, but not all, investment risk to
individual members. Such arrangements include, forexample, sequential or combination hybrids where a
– In DB schemes, there is a risk that employers may
member can join a DB scheme after a period of DC
reduce promised pension benefits ex post (eg, in the
membership, or where they are accruing both DB and
event of bankruptcy). Employees are exposed to this
risk unless a mutual guarantee scheme has been setup (or another subsidy or bail-out mechanism exists)
The distinction between DB and DC is blurring somewhat,
to pick up the pension liabilities of the insolvent
with DB schemes shifting towards structures that have a
employer. If investment in company stock is restricted
DC element, or DC schemes being structured (eg, through
and assets are properly segregated, default risk is not
guarantees or specific investment strategies) to replicate
DB-type outcomes. Thus, the pension structures that areemerging involve a diverse and often complex set of
– DC schemes can have advantages in terms of the
allocations of risks (and responsibilities) between
control they give individuals over their pension assets,
individual scheme members, employers and financial
allowing them flexibility and choice to adjust their
institutions, which often cannot be unambiguously
pensions in line with their needs and preferences. DB
described as being either of DB- or DC-type.
schemes, on the other hand, require individuals toaccumulate the pension in the form of deferred life
Investment risk in DC pension
annuities and thus limit the risk–return choice. While
there are valid concerns about the ability of individuals
DC pension schemes are in essence vehicles for
to exert choice and make the right decisions, this
long-term savings and investment. Contributions are paid
does not necessarily imply that a DB pension provides
into individual accounts and invested over the long term
to deliver a pension upon retirement. For a given level of
There is a spectrum of risks and scheme
contributions, the level of retirement wealth accumulated
structures
depends on the net investment returns accrued in the
Pension scheme design can vary in how the different
account, and hence the performance of the investments
risks are allocated, and the stylised pure DB and DC
Oxera Agenda
The shift towards DC pensions: are the risks overstated?
Distribution of pension wealth accumulated over
mitigated, either by investing in ‘safer’ assets or
40 years under different investment strategies
by shifting the risk to another party (eg, a
financial institution providing a guarantee).
Indeed, in a number of countries, regulationimposes minimum guaranteed returns or other
constraints on pension investment. The result
of such regulation may be investment that is
excessively conservative or inappropriate for
– ‘Safer’ assets (eg, government bonds) may
have lower risks, but also imply lower returns
on average. Holding a significant proportion
of the portfolio in equity during the pension
before retirement) can result in significantlyhigher average retirement wealth, at a comparatively
‘life-cycle’ approach whereby 90% is invested in equity
small increase in the risk of receiving very low levels
(10% in bonds) for the first 30 years, switching to 30%
of retirement wealth, given the long investment
equity (70% bonds) for the remaining ten years until
horizon over which pensions accumulate.
– Minimum return guarantees limit the shortfall risk for
The outcomes under the 100% bonds strategy are
individuals that may result from financial market
clustered at the lower end of the pension wealth
volatility, but they also limit individuals’ participation in
distribution, whereas outcomes are more dispersed
the upside benefits. The cost in terms of forgone
under both the lifestyled or 100% equity approach, with
returns, and hence lower retirement wealth, can be
more pension wealth being accumulated. The differences
significant if the guarantee is used throughout most or
– The median wealth accumulated when investing
The results of a simulation exercise undertaken by Oxera
100% in bonds is around €62,000, which is less than
illustrate these points by quantifying what different
half of the median wealth accumulated when investing
pension asset investment strategies mean in terms of
100% in equity (around €140,000). Given the
wealth accumulation for retirement.2 In the base model, it
bond–equity mix, the wealth accumulated under the
is assumed that the individual (or the employer on behalf
life-cycle approach falls in between (around
of the individual) starts to contribute to the individual
account in the DC plan at the age of 25. The retirementage is 65, so the maximum investment horizon is
– The probability of accumulating pension wealth of
40 years. The assumption is that yearly contributions
more than €90,000 is much higher when the
equal 5% of salary, which starts at €20,000 and grows
investment contains only, or at least some, equity—
annually in real terms at a rate of 2%. The modelling is in
72% of individual accounts that follow the 100%
real terms. The individual account is invested in
equity approach, respectively, accumulate more than
government bonds and equity. The management fee is
€90,000, compared with only 20% of accounts that
set at 1% of assets per year, and returns in the individual
account are assumed to be exempt from tax. The modelis based on a simulation of real bond and equity returns,
An important consideration in pension wealth
with the estimates for the parameters (ie, means,
accumulation is how likely it is that individuals will end
standard deviations, covariance) obtained from historical
up with very low pension wealth or, more generally, how
data.3 Taking the investment strategy, the contribution
variable the outcomes are. Based on the simulations
levels and the asset management fees as given, the
using historical returns, an analysis of the bonds-only
accumulated pension wealth for 10,000 individuals is
investment strategy in terms of the percentage of
then simulated, based on this generalised historical
individuals worse off than the median or bottom
percentiles of the equity-only strategies suggests that:
Figure 2 shows the simulated wealth distribution for
– if the entire portfolio is held in bonds, in 96% of cases
three investment strategies: 100% investment in
the level of pension wealth accumulated is lower than
government bonds; 100% investment in equity; and a
the median level of wealth (about €140,000) under the
Oxera Agenda
The shift towards DC pensions: are the risks overstated?
simulations are after all based on a set of assumptions,
Table 1 Pension wealth accumulated over 20 years
including historical risk–return parameters that may not
under different investment strategies
hold going forward. Rather, the point is a more general
one: there is a trade-off between risk and return, and
limiting risk usually comes at the cost of forgoing
potential returns and retirement wealth. The cost can be
particularly high if the pension assets are invested in
‘safer’ or guaranteed investments over most or all of thepension accumulation phase. Diversifying instead into
equity can deliver higher returns, at comparatively low
equity-only strategy. Investing in bonds delivers a 96%
risk, not in the short run but over the long time horizon,
chance of accumulating less than €140,000, but only
a 50% chance of receiving less than this amount if the
Concluding remarks
In DC pension schemes, investment risk is borne by
– accumulated wealth under the bonds-only strategy is
individual scheme members. This risk can be managed,
lower in 42% of the cases than the bottom tenth
and DC schemes can be designed to deliver outcomes
percentile of wealth (€57,000) under the equity-only
along the broad risk–return spectrum. While there are
strategy. Thus, investing in bonds delivers a 42%
valid policy concerns about pension benefit adequacy,
chance of accumulating less than €57,000, but only a
policymakers should consider the cost of imposing
10% chance if the investment is all in equities.
minimum-return guarantees and other constraints onpension investment. Such constraints can imply
The above results are based on a time horizon for
significant forgone returns and hence lower average
pension accumulation and investment of 40 years.
retirement wealth for individual scheme members. In
However, similar conclusions still apply if the time
addition, over long time periods, the additional reduction
horizon in the simulation model is shortened to 20 years.
in the risk of an unfavourable outcome that is actually
Table 1 summarises the results of the simulations,
achieved by investing in ‘low-risk’ securities may be
holding all other assumptions the same, but shortening
minimal. Constraints on pension investment restrict the
risk–return set available for individual scheme membersand may result in a lack of innovation in the product
The outcomes are, on average, still better when the
investment strategy involves at least some investment inequity, and even the ‘bad’ outcomes still deliver higher
Product solutions are being developed in the market that
wealth than under the bonds-only strategy in the majority
are designed to suit the retirement needs of individuals
of cases. For example, for the lowest tenth percentile of
and their risk–return preferences, ranging from life-cycle
outcomes under the equity-only strategy, retirement
investment approaches to tailored investment solutions
wealth is €18,915, which is still higher than the lowest
that seek to achieve specific retirement outcomes for
tenth percentile under the bonds-only strategy (€16,155).
individuals, taking account of relevant factors such as
Indeed, the probability of a worse outcome under the
age, retirement date or the expected public pension of
equity-only strategy is less than 1% for a 20-year
individuals. Further research into how DC pension
investment period (and less than 0.1% for a
investment can be tailored to meet individuals’ retirement
needs would no doubt be useful, and new productsolutions are likely to develop accordingly.
The aim of this is not to advocate a particular form ofinvestment for DC pension scheme assets—the
1 A simplified example can illustrate this point. A worker who accumulates four periods of final salary DB pension benefits with four employers,where the reference salary is the (real) final salary that the worker has with each employer, will receive less pension than someone with exactlythe same wage path who stays with the same employer, if their real wages increase with age. With a salary of 20,000, 25,000, 30,000 and35,000 at the end of each subsequent ten-year period, and a defined benefit of 1/80th of the final salary per year worked, the job mover obtainsa pension of 13,750, compared with 17,500 for the worker who stayed with the same employer. 2 The detailed assumptions and further results are described in Oxera (2008), ‘Defined-contribution Pension Schemes: Risks and Advantages forOccupational Retirement Provision’, a report prepared for the European Fund and Asset Management Association, January. 3 Barclays Equity and Gilt indices are used; annual total returns, including income reinvested, on these indices are provided in Barclays Capital(2006), ‘Equity Gilt Study 2006’. Estimates for 1900–2005 are used. In this period, mean (arithmetic average) log real returns for equities andbonds were 5.14% and 1.15%, respectively; standard deviations were 19.4% and 13.2%; and the covariance between equity and bond returnswas 1.54%. The results for different time periods would have been similar. For example, estimates for 1950–2005 would have been: 6.75% and1.34% mean real log returns for equity and gilts; 22.85% and 12.56% standard deviation; and 1.6% covariance. Although simulations areparameterised with estimates based on log real returns, the simulated series are transformed back to levels, and the return on investments isthen calculated.
Oxera Agenda
The shift towards DC pensions: are the risks overstated?
If you have any questions regarding the issues raised in this article, please contact the editor, Derek Holt: tel +44 (0) 1865 253 000 or email [email protected] Other articles in the February issue of Agenda include: malaise in the markets: the impact of equity volatility set free by competition? transitional access regulation of telecoms incumbents untangling FRAND: what price intellectual property? For details of how to subscribe to Agenda, please email [email protected], or visit our website
Oxera, 2008. All rights reserved. Except for the quotation of short passages for the purposes of criticism or review, no part may beused or reproduced without permission. Oxera Agenda
Healthy eating for people with depression, anxiety and related disorders fact sheet 30 Food can play a vital role in maintaining mental health as wel as physical health. In general, eating a nourishing diet gives people an overal sense of wel -being. There are also some specific nutritional strategies that can help improve mood, maintain healthy brain functioning and help people with
Recept 1 - Leegte Qi Ren Shen – radix ginseng: 8 gram, drie keer per dag opschenken Leegte Qi/Xue Long Yan Cha – longanthee (drakenoogjes),stoom dit fruit eerst (5 tot 10 stukjes) en schenk er dan heet water over, drink al een het water Hong Zao Yang Xue Cha – rode dadel bloedvoedende thee, 10 rode dadels met 10 gram suiker in water koken, maak groene thee, laat 5 min. t